Active investment management’s weekly magazine for fee-based advisors

Article highlights

  • Inflation is not a one-off change in the price level caused by a short-term distortion to protect profit margins but is a persistent acceleration in prices.
  • Pundits who are talking incessantly about the “Roaring Twenties” never tell anyone that for the next decade the economy was in a period of mild deflation and long-term bond yields actually fell 150 basis points.
  • There is a 75% inverse correlation between the debt ratio and core inflation—the debt morass ends up being a future drag on real GDP growth and hence the downward pull on inflation and interest rates.
  • Post-summer, expect to see production expand, demand growth recede, and all this inflation chatter quiet down—and the case for a bull-flattener in the Treasury market will be very strong in that environment.
  • It’ll be interesting to see what aggregate demand growth looks like in the future with an ongoing resource gap in the labor market and a consumer base that is tapped out when it comes to durable goods expenditure.
As time goes by (The fundamental things apply)

Let me just start with what inflation is and what it isn’t.

Inflation is not a one-off change in the price level caused by a short-term distortion to protect profit margins but is a persistent acceleration in prices. It is a condition that lasts for years; it is not temporary. And I am not going to debate whether we are seeing a deviation in the fundamental trend line since we clearly are now and likely will be for the next several months.

But the trend line has not changed because of the pandemic; there has never been a natural disaster or a policy response to a natural disaster that ushered in a permanent change in the inflation trend. All they do is create short-term disturbances, distortions, and deviations. I think we must look at the pandemic in that light—a natural disaster on a global scale that has a huge impact on supply and demand and generates huge disturbances, but they are not permanent.

Nobody has suffered more natural disasters in the past decade than Japan, which has endured over 100 earthquakes, typhoons, and floods. Yet its inflation rate has gone from +0.2% to -0.2% over that time, and that’s even with the fiscal spigots turned on to such an extent that its government debt-to-GDP ratio has ballooned from 180% to 225%.

FIGURE 1: GOOGLE SEARCHES FOR “INFLATION”

Sources: Google Trends, Rosenberg Research

You don’t have to rely on Japan. Look at what happened to inflation coming out of the global pandemic of 1918–1919. The pundits out there now, who are talking incessantly about the “Roaring Twenties” as their new post-COVID-19 theme, never seem to tell anyone that for the next decade, the economy was in a period of mild deflation, not hyperinflation, and long-term bond yields actually fell 150 basis points.

Ben

Let’s look at what the price level did from August 1979 to August 1987 under Fed Chairman Paul Volcker, the inflation dragon slayer. It soared 55%. Yet he is renowned for killing inflation. How can that be when the Consumer Price Index (CPI) jumped 55%? Well, the inflation rate went from 11.8% at the time he started to 4.3% when he was done—so it is the second derivative that matters most. The change in the change. And driving the inflation rate to the ground was exactly his goal.

Now, what about Ben Bernanke? All he wanted to do was reflate through 90% of his eight-year tenure. Yet the CPI actually rose by less during his time as chairman—the price level rose 18%, but the inflation rate slowed from 3.6% to 1.1%. And he did everything from ZIRP to repeated QE to get the inflation ball rolling. People seem to think that policymakers have some magic wand—it’s rather incredible.

The same economists crying about inflation now were doing the exact same thing coming out of the Great Financial Crisis. Then we had a 10-year period of flat-to-negative real policy rates, even under Powell, who tried unsuccessfully to normalize interest rates. But think of all the inflation talk we had after Donald Trump got elected in 2016—populism, nationalism, protectionism, tariff hikes, trade frictions, the end of globalization, massive tax cuts and a $1 trillion deficit that co-existed somehow with a 3.5% unemployment rate (a 50-year low). Yet we never did get much of an inflationary impulse in terms of wages and underlying consumer inflation.

What a drag it is getting old
What the pandemic has not changed are the secular disinflation fundamentals that have been around for decades. These are still in full force. The aging of the population is one; the fastest-growing segment of the population that is also grabbing the highest share is the 65-years-and-up cohort, and this trend will continue for the next decade. While there are some folks who claim this is inflationary from the supply side, they ignore the much more powerful effect this has on aggregate demand because no other age category has seen such a sudden decline in annual expenditures than this segment of the population, whose share will continue to rise. This will act as a pervasive negative influence on aggregate demand growth and inflation until at least 2030. Much of the industrialized world and China face this similar demographic challenge, and we already know the impact of aging populations on inflation from Japan’s experience.
FIGURE 2: CONSUMER SPENDING THROUGH THE LIFE CYCLE

Sources: Haver Analytics, Rosenberg Research

Video killed the radio star

The accelerating pace of technological change has not changed either and is actually picking up momentum during this pandemic as businesses figured out they can do more with less labor input. Here we had the worst economy since 1946 last year, and yet business volume spending on automation, IT equipment, and software expanded more than 6%. The share of business spending on productivity enhancements in the past 15 months has risen to an all-time high. And so, look at what is happening fundamentally in the real economy, and we saw this in spades in the first quarter, where productivity accelerated at a 4% year-over-year rate, or double the historical trend. It is still too early to make a complete assessment here as to whether we have seen a structural improvement in productivity, but it certainly is possible.

We have GDP back to record highs and employment still down more than 8%. Productivity, which was so lacking in the 1970s, is an inflation killer. It has a 40% inverse correlation with the year-over-year trend in consumer prices, total and core, because of the dampening impact on labor costs, which is the mother’s milk for inflation. The correlation between productivity and inflation, over cycles, is 40 times more powerful than commodity prices. Keep in mind that we have seen no fewer than 15 commodity cycles in the past six decades, and they all look like a recurring sequence of sine waves. And each time, the inflationists claim that we are about to embark on a “commodity supercycle.” Twice in the last decade or so, we have seen the oil price soar above $100 per barrel. Each time, the underlying trend in inflation was not impaired.

Another day older and deeper in debt

And then, of course, we have the greatest inflation killer of all, which is excessive indebtedness. The all-economy debt-to-GDP ratio crossed above 250% back in the dot-com bubble and that was the threshold at which the growth in aggregate demand was impaired by the chokehold of extreme levels of indebtedness.

We have the law of diminishing marginal utility as it pertains to debt decades ago, and we will come out of the pandemic with debt across the household, business, and government sectors at an unprecedented 370% of GDP. This already takes out the bubble peak of the late 2000s, which proved to be the most pervasive constraint on growth, inflation, and interest rates in the 2009–2019 cycle.

This debt ratio has exploded 40 percentage points in the span of a year. That has never happened before. As I said, we crossed the 250% threshold three decades ago. My research shows this to be an important cutoff point. Since that time, the credit multiplier has broken down, the loan-to-deposit ratio in the banking system has broken down, and money velocity has broken down and rendered the monetary aggregates a pretty useless set of statistics on their own, in the context of contracting money velocity, which is ongoing.

Since we crossed the Rubicon of the total debt-to-GDP ratio exceeding 250% three decades ago, we have since experienced a 50% inverse correlation between debt accumulation and real GDP growth. The positive correlation between credit and the economy ended many years, in fact, decades ago. This is something lost on not only this administration but the prior three as well. Some say that debt is affordable because interest rates are so low, but the causation runs the other way. Because the debt situation is so onerous, interest rates must stay extremely low to prevent the economic and financial system from collapsing, as we saw, for example, when bond yields got as high as 5%-plus in the summer of 2007 and to 3%-plus in late 2018. There is a reason why these levels of market interest rates were unsustainable, even in the context of what appeared to be an economy operating at or near full employment.

FIGURE 3: DEBT OUTSTANDING AS A SHARE OF GDP

Note: Shading indicates recession.

Sources: Haver Analytics, Rosenberg Research

Most people don’t know this, but the new paradigm of debt and growth and interest rates began in 1990, in the aftermath of the advent of the leveraged buyout cycle, which once existed on the fringes of the financial system and is now endemic. The causation runs the other way. Higher debt growth past a certain limit is deflationary and exerts downward pressure on interest rates. In the past three decades, we have seen a 90% inverse correlation between the all-economy debt-to-GDP ratio and the 10-year Treasury note yield. There is a 75% inverse correlation between the debt ratio and core inflation. The debt morass and adding to it ends up being a future drag on real GDP growth and hence the downward pull on inflation and interest rates. Because today’s investors live in the here and now and don’t have the same time horizons that used to exist before assets became trading vehicles, they don’t see what is going to happen around the bend.

Joe Biden’s desire to rewrite the social contract with massive spending and debt may well level the playing field and make a whole lot of people better off; however, the historical record shows that this will not produce better economic outcomes. If a level playing field and larger government incursion into the economy were truly generators of better economic outcomes, then the Soviet Empire would not have collapsed and the leaders of economic growth in these past few decades would have been Italy, Greece, Portugal, and Japan.

Shock the monkey

At the same time, the way I see the situation, we are still in the grips of excess capacity in the product and labor markets. The truth is, there has been nothing quite like the disruption caused by the pandemic. The initial shock hit demand more than supply, so we had a temporary deflation shock to the global economy. Last spring, the three-month trend in the CPI was -4%, the three-month trend in the Producer Price Index (PPI) was -8% at an annual rate, and commodity prices were in a nosedive. Did that create the conditions for some persistent deflationary experience? Of course not. But the same holds true for the distortion we are now seeing in the opposite direction.

Now with the reopening and fiscal juice boosting demand ahead of supply, we have a temporary inflationary situation on our hands that will get resolved in the second half of the year. It may take some time, as Jay Powell told us at the last FOMC meeting. And for all the bond bears and inflation-phobes out there who extrapolate the present into the future and gaze at the various purchasing manager surveys, the statement that resonated the most was that nobody should claim that they have a more extensive network of business contacts than the Fed has at its disposal. And while Joe Biden and his band of fiscal adventurers think they have a mandate to use the pandemic as a means to have government infiltrate the economy, the 2022 midterms will have a say in how long this lasts, as Clinton found out the hard way in 1994, Obama in 2010, and Trump in 2018.

It is 100% true that this time around, the pandemic has triggered supply chain disruptions, and the lingering effects of COVID-19 have restricted the supply of some key materials. This is also the case on the labor front—though there is more than ample supply of idle workers waiting in the wings whether in manufacturing, construction, resources, or consumer cyclical services. It is tough for me to wrap my head around the concept of a labor shortage when we have a total of 17 million available labor resources and that runs 6 million deeper than was the case a year ago. That is just a fact. Maybe there are constraints on freeing up those resources right now, but I do not see this as being anything more than a temporary situation that has continued to be influenced by the pandemic and the policy response to the pandemic.

While we are seeing companies in some sectors offering up pay sweeteners and signing bonuses—and as we saw in Friday’s payroll report, some hefty wage increases to lure workers back in—keep in mind that a lot of this labor that is being held back will not be held back come September when the extended federal jobless benefits expire, assuming they do expire, and when schools and day care centers fully open up (freeing up more of the female labor cohort). It has been very evident in the data that people have not returned to the labor force in full because of lingering health concerns, but again, moving from 40% vaccination rates to 75% by the end of the summer is going to rectify this anomaly.

It is amazing to me that most economists spend most of their time looking at the trees instead of the forest past the trees. This is also the case with food, though inclement weather conditions (in Brazil but also in key growing parts of the U.S.) have played a role here in terms of pricing, not to mention the traders in the futures and options pits trying to make a quick buck as the net speculative long positions in corn, wheat, and soybeans have been soaring to the moon. But with a lag, the basic laws of economics will reassert themselves, in that the vaccination success will help ease up whatever shortages seem to exist in the jobs market. And on the demand side, one can reasonably expect the end of the stimulus checks and uber-generous unemployment benefits in the third quarter to exert a sharp dampening influence.

As for further fiscal stimulus from the Biden team, including infrastructure, these latest proposals are already being met with some resistance in Congress, including some factions within the Democratic Party. So post-summer, expect to see production expand, demand growth recede, and all this price inflation chatter to quiet down. The case for a bull-flattener in the Treasury market will be very strong in that environment, all the more so since vibrant growth, accelerated inflation, and an early return to Fed tightening have already been priced in.

FIGURE 4: LABOR SUPPLY

Note: Shading indicates recession.

Sources: Haver Analytics, Rosenberg Research

The best things in life are free

One very important element in all of this is where the new equilibrium personal savings rate levels off at once all the distortions play out. It goes without saying that it isn’t going to remain at 27.6%. And it is only there because government transfers have boomed 148% in the past year—real incomes excluding these fiscal giveaways are running barely above 1% on a year-over-year basis. We are now in a situation where consumer cyclical expenditures have recouped 70% of the huge loss but are still 20% below pre-pandemic peaks. But much of this spending is lost forever since there are only so many visits to restaurants, bars, salons, sporting events, movies, and so on, that we can make in a given week, month, or year, not to mention how many vacations we can really afford to take.

And then there is this other little matter that has accentuated the shortages of materials: the unprecedented consumer spending on durable goods during this crisis—soaring 44% in the year to March and well over 20% above the pre-COVID-19 peak. And keep in mind that this segment of personal consumption expenditure is more than double the areas of services that are primed for a post-COVID-19 recovery. That so-called pent-down demand, since nobody is building another deck in the backyard or fitting a second table in the dining room, may well provide a huge offset to the service sector rebound. What we then end up with is the government deficit bumping against massive surplus savings in the household sector, which then splashes a lot of cold water on the hawkish inflation and bearish interest views that have dominated the market narrative for much of this year.

And nobody I know is calling for a return to a 3.5% jobless rate, and yet we never did experience a normal wage and inflation cycle when we hit that 50-year low in late 2019 and early 2020. The last time we had a 3.5% unemployment rate, back in 1969, core inflation was 6% and the trend in wages was 6.5%. At this last go-around just over a year ago, core inflation was barely higher than 2% and the trend in wages was just over 3%. The Phillips curve has flattened over time, and it isn’t clear to me yet that stimulus checks, vaccines, and even future infrastructure are going to change the shape of that curve in any meaningful way. And yet, even with the unemployment rate not seen getting back to that low of 3.5%, the market somehow thought the funds rate is getting back to the peak of the last cycle, and the same for inflation. Just another way of saying a whole cycle of Fed tightening and peak inflation from the 2009–2019 period is already being discounted. The risk-reward ratio in bonds is tilted in a bullish pattern, all the more so since it has reemerged as the most detested asset class. I understand that is an out-of-consensus view, but this is only an acknowledgment that there is a lot priced into bonds at the current time. Too much, from my viewpoint.

You have to ask yourself, if a 50-year low 3.5% unemployment rate couldn’t generate a normal wage and price inflation cycle—and a normal Fed rates cycle—then how will anything above that do the trick?

Out of the gap

For all the talk of pervasive shortages and disrupted supply chains, this is also not a permanent situation. Production of semiconductors out of Taiwan and Korea is booming, as are exports in general. Lumber activity in Canada is soaring. The containers off the ports of LA and Long Beach are filled to the brim and ready to be unloaded. So, just as the fiscal stimulus wanes and the reopening effect on demand subsides in the second half of the year, the supply will be coming back with a lag. I keep hearing once again about the end of globalization, and yet world trade volumes have just managed to hit records both in level terms and as a share of GDP.

FIGURE 5: TRADE VOLUME

Note: Shading indicates recession.

Sources: Haver Analytics, Rosenberg Research

And then there is just the basic math. Any elementary course in economics will teach you that the price of labor, wages, and other compensation, should rise at a rate roughly equal to productivity growth plus inflation in an economy that is truly at this full-employment equilibrium.

With productivity growth climbing at 4%, maximum employment and stable inflation will only occur when wages are running at a sustained rate of about 6%. Today, total labor compensation growth is below 3%, meaning that there is likely still considerable slack in the labor market. This is exactly the point that Powell is making. I think at the next post-meeting Q&A press conference, he should just wheel out an old-fashioned chalkboard and show the math to everyone so they can understand this basic principle. We have a broad U-6 unemployment rate of 10.4%, and inflation does not become a pervasive problem until this measure approaches 8%; and the industrywide capacity utilization rate is 74%, and inflation here does not become a persistent experience until it nears 78%.

FIGURE 6: U-6 UNEMPLOYMENT RATE

Note: Shading indicates recession.

Sources: Haver Analytics, Rosenberg Research

There have only been two other times in the past four decades when we had the U-6 unemployment and capacity utilization rates at these levels at the same time: November 2001 and September 2008. I am not sure you wanted to be thinking about sustainable inflation and a new higher path for interest rates in those periods. Let’s just say that what these metrics speak to is an output gap of over 1% in the same quarter that that GDP growth is going to peak and then succumb to intense moderation as the stimulus checks wear off. This means all the inflation risks going forward, fundamentally speaking, are to the downside because I think there is a good chance that after having never closed the output gap in all this policy stimulus, the deflationary output gap is going to rear its head again. This is not priced into any asset class, and I think this may be the principal risk to the risk-on inflation narrative.
Take the money and run

One also has to remember that when forecasting interest rates, it is not the fiscal deficit alone that matters, but the entire savings pie relative to desired spending and investment. So while the deficit boom has resulted in the federal government having “dissaved” by $3 trillion over the past year, household savings have ballooned $4 trillion and the net savings in the corporate sector have expanded $100 billion (internally generated cash flows minus capital spending).

In other words, we are still stuck in a savings glut, and it remains to be seen just how profligate Congress will be in the future and just how much consumers are going to unleash their savings cache in view of the fact that the spending spree we will see in services is likely to be short-lived and that there is no pent-up demand for the much larger (more than double) market for household durable goods.

I keep hearing the terms “dry powder” and “pent-up demand.” What makes you think that money gets spent after the flurry of spending on durables these past 12 months?

The assumption is that these savings have to get spent. Why is that? There is no pent-up demand for virtually every component of durable goods consumption. We have had this unusual situation where in a recession, spending on durable goods soared. The year-over-year trend today of over 40% is the strongest since 1950. At the same time, just as people start spending more on restaurants, theme parks, travel, and entertainment, we are completely maxed out on goods consumption. Here we are, a year after the economic trough, and spending volume on consumer goods is more than 12% higher than it was before the downturn began.

It took six years to accomplish that coming out of the 2008–2009 Great Financial Crisis and three years following the 1990–1991 and 2001–2002 economic downturns. If you were to ever look at the chart of household ownership of durable goods assets per capita, the change in the past year to unprecedented levels looks like a dot-com stock from 1999. I kid you not. At the same time, the production of consumer goods is flat year over year but expanding nonetheless—up 17% from the trough, which is half the pace of consumer goods demand. But we will very likely see production become better realigned in the second half of the year. The process is already underway even if the bond bears and inflation-phobes use the Commodity Research Bureau (CRB) Index as their primary focal point.

FIGURE 7: CORE CPI & CRB COMMODITY PRICE INDEX

Note: Shading indicates recession.

Sources: Haver Analytics, Rosenberg Research

We’ll see where the new post-pandemic personal savings rate levels out. Something tells me it will be a lot higher than the pre-COVID-19 level of 7%, just as that 7% was higher than the 5% savings rate that existed before the Great Financial Crisis.
New York, New York

And we can see this shift in preferences toward saving in the data. Look at the New York Fed’s tracking. Maybe this is why Biden felt the need to go big. Less than 25% of these stimulus checks are going into the real economy, and that share is going down with each fiscal package. One-third is going to pay down debt and over 40% is being saved, which is code for opening a Robinhood account. Either way, no assessment of where inflation is going can be done without some estimate of where the new post-pandemic personal savings rate is going to level off. Something tells me as a student of economic behavior that it is going to remain very high for an extended period of time.

In fact, the secular change in how households, not businesses or governments, have approached their balance sheets coming out of the Great Financial Crisis is most likely not going to change. This doesn’t mean that free money from the government won’t be spent, but what is most striking is that less than 25% of these stimulus checks have been finding their way into the economy. It will be interesting to see what aggregate demand growth looks like in the future with an ongoing resource gap in the labor market, a consumer base that is tapped out when it comes to durable goods expenditure, and the end of the gravy train when it comes to gargantuan fiscal stimulus. Though I’ll admit that ending the gravy train will probably end up resting on Joe Manchin’s vote and whether he represents his conservative state of West Virginia or the left-leaning UBI advocates of his own party.

Editor’s note: Proactive Advisor Magazine would like to thank Rosenberg Research for permission to publish this edited and condensed version of their article. The article in full form was first published at Rosenberg Research on May 14, 2021.

One month of free access to premium content from Rosenberg Research is available here.

The opinions expressed in this article are those of the author and do not necessarily represent the views of Proactive Advisor Magazine. These opinions are presented for educational purposes only.

David Rosenberg is the president and chief economist and strategist of Rosenberg Research & Associates Inc., an economic consulting firm established in 2020. From 2009 to 2019, Mr. Rosenberg was chief economist and strategist at Gluskin Sheff + Associates Inc. He also has been the chief North American economist at Merrill Lynch in New York and chief economist and strategist for Merrill Lynch Canada. He was consistently ranked in the Institutional Investor All-Star analyst rankings, and he and his team placed first in the Brendan Wood survey of Canadian economists for 10 years in a row. Mr. Rosenberg is a contributor to major financial publications and makes frequent TV appearances.

Recent Posts:
LinkedIn
Share